The Australian National University

AUSTRALIA & JAPAN IN THE REGION

Forum of the Australia-Japan Research Centre (AJRC)
Crawford School of Public Policy


Volume 4, No 2, February 2016 View in your web browser

The Bank of Japan’s sub-zero shock

By Masahiko Takeda, Hitotsubashi University

Governor Haruhiko Kuroda of the Bank of Japan (BoJ) announced on 29 January that the BoJ would apply a negative interest rate of minus 0.1 per cent to deposits that financial institutions hold at the Bank, starting from 16 February.

Surprised by this move, the yen–US dollar exchange rate, which had appreciated to the 117–118 yen per US dollar range earlier this year, immediately weakened to 121 yen per US dollar. The 10-year Japanese government bond (JGB) yield, which was 0.22 per cent on the day before the announcement, dropped sharply to a historic low of 0.06 per cent. The yield on shorter-term JGBs of up to eight years turned negative. Clearly the market impact has been remarkable.

Clearly the market impact has been remarkable.

Negative interest rates mean that lenders have to pay interest, instead of receiving it. This is mind-boggling to an old-timer like me, who was taught that nominal interest rates could not be negative. The simple logic behind this proposition is that if interest rates were negative, lenders would not lend and instead hold cash, giving them a zero per cent nominal yield. With no lenders, interest rates cannot be sub-zero. But, financial institutions aren’t withdrawing their deposits with the BoJ because the BoJ’s new measure includes a mechanism that penalizes withdrawals in cash. Therefore, if financial institutions want to avoid the negative rate on their deposits, they need to use them by lending to their customers or buying assets from the market. Inducing them to do so is one of the intentions of the new policy.

Another intention is to push down market interest rates. But why negative JGB yields? Any investor can do better by holding cash than by buying JGBs at negative rates. Because of this one might think there would be no one willing to buy JGBs at sub-zero rates, and hence yields cannot fall below zero. So it seems that once market interest rates are close to zero, the BoJ cannot push them down further. To see why this logic doesn’t hold, we need to review what the BoJ has been doing over the past three years.

One might think there would be no one willing to buy JGBs at sub-zero rates, and hence yields cannot fall below zero.

Shortly after Kuroda took office in March 2013, the BoJ began its ‘Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing’ (QQE) strategy. One of the key components of QQE was large-scale purchases of JGBs and other assets, aimed at doubling the size of the BoJ’s balance sheet in two years. After this was achieved, the BoJ kept buying assets. Its current pace is 80 trillion yen (about US$679 billion) per year. Such a massive and continuous asset purchase has pushed JGB yields down and, since September 2014, the BoJ has been buying JGBs at negative interest rates to achieve its quantitative target.

If the BoJ stands ready to do this, so do financial market participants, because they know they can pass the assets they buy on to the BoJ at even lower interest rates (that is, at even higher prices than they paid to buy them). Negative rates started from the very short end of the yield curve in 2014, and by December last year, the sub-zero range reached three-year JGBs. The BoJ’s recent action substantially expanded the sub-zero range, because it signalled to the market the BoJ’s determination to push the already super-low interest rates even lower through its market operations.

That the BoJ’s policy action this time was not quantity-based but price-based is a testament to QQE’s failure to achieve its stated objective: an inflation rate of 2 per cent within two years. Almost three years have passed since QQE’s inception, but inflation has been barely positive in recent months. It has been amply proven that a massive injection of liquidity does not dramatically boost demand or robustly push up inflation. This was true when quantitative easing was first used by the BoJ in the 2000s, has been true in the United States and is likely to be true in the Euro zone as well. Hence, the BoJ’s change of tactics is understandable.

Yet the key question is will the negative interest rate on BoJ deposits effectively create inflationary momentum? As noted above, it did have a sizable financial market impact. But so has QQE, under which the yen has weakened very substantially and market interest rates have fallen, some of them to sub-zero. Still, these financial effects have not translated into sufficient ‘real’ effects on the economy. It is still too early to say, but one cannot be too optimistic about this time being different.

Yet the key question is will the negative interest rate on BoJ deposits effectively create inflationary momentum?

Another angle to assess the BoJ’s recent action is the scope for further easing. Governor Kuroda has been publicly saying that there is no limit to the BoJ’s ability to ease monetary policy, in spite of the increasingly visible shortage of assets the BoJ could buy from the market under QQE. By shifting to a ‘price’ measure, the BoJ might be able to continue its easing, diving deeper into negative interest rates if necessary. Then, eventually, inflation might be ignited.

The BoJ under Governor Kuroda should be credited for its courage to break a taboo and introduce negative interest rates, first through its market operations and now with its deposits. But this policy makes many, including myself, uncomfortable. Market operations at negative interest rates mean that the lender (the BoJ) is giving out money to borrowers for free in addition to zero-interest rate loans. These borrowers are not the poorest of the population, but renowned financial institutions who should not be relying on such freebies for their profits.

Unquestionably, there are better ways to use public money. But this is the government’s rather than the central bank’s responsibility. To reinvigorate the Japanese economy and ensure its sustainability, the government can do many things, some of which do not even require expending budget resources. It appears that the BoJ is being pushed over the edge, trying to achieve something that might be more suitably and effectively achieved by other means.

About the author

Masahiko Takeda is a professor in the School of International and Public Policy, Hitotsubashi

About AJRC

The Australia-Japan Research Centre (AJRC) at Crawford School of Public Policy conducts research to explore and improve understanding of the economies and economic policy processes in Australia and Japan and both countries' strategic interests in the Asia Pacific economy. Its policy-oriented areas of interest cover developments in regional economic cooperation and integration and encompass research on trade, finance, macroeconomics and structural and regulatory reform, as well as international economic relations.

Forthcoming Events

  • Brown Bag Seminar, ANU
    18 February, Professor Mie Oba, Tokyo University of Science
  • Australia-Japan Security Cooperation Workshop, ANU
    19 February, [run by Dr Tomohiko Satake, Visiting Fellow AJRC]
  • Japan, Australia and Regional Security Architecture public lecture, ANU
    19 February, more information
  • Brown Bag Seminar, ANU
    2 March, Professor Shujiro Urata, Waseda University
  • Issues in Finance and Macroeconomics Conference
    22-23 March, [run by Associate Professor Tatsuyoshi Okimoto, Research Director AJRC]

For more information, visit the AJRC website.

Recent publications

  • Abe's arrows still missing the mark
    By Nobumasa Akiyama
    AJIR Forum
    No.1, 2016
    » download
  • Japan’s Abenomics bumps along
    By Hugh Patrick
    AJIR Forum
    No.12, 2015
    » download
  • Will Japan’s corporate governance reform work?`
    By Bruce Greenwald
    AJIR Forum
    No.11, 2015
    » download
  • Has Japan’s corporate governance reform worked?
    By Masao Nakamura
    AJIR Forum
    No.10, 2015
    » download

Contact AJRC

(T) +61 2 6125 0168
(F) +61 2 6125 8448
(E) ajrc@anu.edu.au

Australia-Japan Research Centre (AJRC)
Crawford School of Public Policy
ANU College of Asia & the Pacific

J.G. Crawford Building No. 132
Lennox Crossing Road
The Australian National University
Canberra ACT 0200 Australia

Disclaimer:

No part of this publication may be reproduced in whole or in part without written permission from the Executive Director of the Australia Japan Research Centre.

The views and opinions expressed in this publication reflect the author's point of view only and not necessarily those of the Australia Japan Research Centre and the Crawford School of Public Policy, The Australian National University.


The Australian National University, Canberra | CRICOS Provider : 00120C | ABN : 52 234 063 906


If you do not wish to receive future emails from us, please unsubscribe.